Nearly Right

America's semiconductor bailout reveals the limits of free-market ideology

How Intel's rescue signals the US embrace of state capitalism in strategic industries

The ideological whiplash was swift and stark. One week, Republican leaders condemned Democratic policies as dangerous socialism. The next, they announced the US government would buy 10% of Intel for $8.9 billion, transforming what should have been grants into direct state ownership of a failing technology company.

The contradiction runs deeper than political opportunism. This intervention marks America's grudging admission that market forces alone cannot secure technological supremacy in an era of strategic competition with China.

The stakes could not be higher. America now depends on Taiwan for 90% of the world's most advanced semiconductors—the chips that power everything from iPhones to F-35 fighter jets. This dependence would be merely inconvenient if Taiwan were safely tucked away in the middle of the Pacific. Instead, it sits 100 miles from mainland China, within easy reach of Chinese missiles and an increasingly assertive Beijing that considers the island a breakaway province.

Intel was supposed to be America's insurance policy. The company once dominated global chip manufacturing with the kind of technological superiority that made competitors irrelevant. Now its new chief executive has essentially issued an ultimatum: find us major customers or we'll abandon cutting-edge manufacturing altogether. For American policymakers, this amounts to being held hostage by their own supposed champion.

The government's response—buying equity rather than simply writing grants—signals that conventional policy tools have failed to address the scale of modern technological competition.

The mechanics of American state capitalism

The Intel deal breaks new ground for American industrial policy. Congress designed the CHIPS Act as traditional corporate welfare—$39 billion in grants for companies that promised to build semiconductor fabs on American soil. Recipients would meet milestones, accept oversight, and share profits if they exceeded projections. Standard stuff.

The equity conversion changes everything. Instead of handing Intel money with strings attached, the government becomes a fellow traveller with skin in the game. The $8.9 billion buys 10% of Intel along with something more valuable, aligned incentives. The government waived profit-sharing requirements and clawback provisions in exchange for ownership. These shares cannot vote while the government holds them, but that technicality misses the point. Ownership means influence, and influence flows through channels that extend far beyond shareholder meetings.

This isn't America's first dance with state ownership. During the 2008 financial crisis, the government acquired 60.8% of General Motors and substantial stakes in banks and insurers. Those interventions came with a crucial difference, they were sold as temporary emergency measures during systemic collapse. The Intel deal represents strategic planning for permanent technological competition—a fundamentally different use of state power.

The international precedents are everywhere once you start looking. France maintains ownership stakes in aerospace, energy, and telecommunications. Singapore's sovereign wealth fund holds positions across sectors deemed strategically important. Germany's state of Lower Saxony owns 11.8% of Volkswagen. What seemed like American exceptionalism now looks more like American provincialism.

Intel's credibility crisis

Intel's problems run deeper than technology. The company's manufacturing processes have actually improved dramatically—its latest 18A technology rivals anything TSMC produces. The real crisis is trust.

Potential customers remember Intel's years of broken promises. Delayed chip launches. Missed performance targets. Manufacturing processes that failed to deliver promised improvements. When Intel's CEO promises delivery dates or specifications now, industry veterans mentally add 12 months and subtract 20% performance.

TSMC built its dominance the old-fashioned way, reliable execution over decades. When Apple needed chips for the iPhone, TSMC delivered on time, at scale, with yields that made the economics work. Intel, focused on its own processor designs, never developed that customer-first mentality. Running a foundry isn't just about having the best machines—it's about convincing customers to bet their entire product roadmap on your ability to execute flawlessly.

This creates a vicious cycle. Without major customers, Intel cannot justify the massive investments required to stay competitive in advanced manufacturing. But without those investments, customers have no reason to trust Intel with their most critical chips. Private markets cannot solve this coordination problem because the stakes are too high and the timelines too long.

Government ownership aims to break this cycle by removing Intel's exit option. If the company were purely private, rational calculation might lead it to abandon manufacturing and become another chip design house using TSMC's services—exactly what AMD did successfully after its own manufacturing struggles. State ownership signals that retreat is not an option, giving customers confidence that Intel's capabilities will persist regardless of quarterly earnings pressure.

Beyond Taiwan: the broader vulnerability

The laser focus on Taiwan obscures a more complex reality, modern semiconductors require a global supply chain that no single country controls. The Netherlands' ASML builds the only machines capable of producing cutting-edge chips. Japan supplies essential materials and components. South Korea dominates memory production. Even if Intel successfully rebuilds American manufacturing, the broader ecosystem remains globally distributed and vulnerable.

China grasps this complexity in ways American policymakers apparently do not. Rather than betting on single companies, Chinese strategy systematically addresses every layer of the supply chain through coordinated state investment, technology transfer requirements, and market access restrictions. The results speak for themselves, Chinese companies now achieve manufacturing capabilities that seemed impossible a decade ago.

America's Intel-centric approach resembles trying to rebuild an automotive industry by rescuing one assembly plant whilst ignoring suppliers of engines, electronics, and materials. You preserve some capability whilst failing to address fundamental vulnerabilities.

The competition extends beyond manufacturing to design, software, and systems integration—areas where government ownership provides no advantage. Nvidia dominates artificial intelligence chips through software innovation, not manufacturing prowess. Taking equity stakes in foundries does nothing to address these broader competitive challenges where America's advantages remain substantial but unprotected.

The precedent and its implications

American capitalism has always evolved through crisis, not ideology. World War II brought unprecedented government coordination of industrial production. The space race required massive state investment in technologies that private markets would never have developed. The internet emerged from defence research that treated technological capability as national security, not market opportunity.

Each transformation involved temporary abandonment of market orthodoxy. What makes this moment different is the explicit, permanent nature of the shift. Previous interventions were sold as emergency exceptions to normal operations. The Intel deal signals routine state involvement in strategic industries.

This creates both opportunity and peril. Strategic coordination can accelerate development and address market failures that private investment cannot solve. China's success across multiple high-technology sectors proves the model's potential when executed competently.

But state ownership introduces political considerations that distort economic decision-making. Will Intel face pressure to maintain unprofitable operations in swing states? Will technological choices reflect strategic merit or congressional preferences? The non-voting share structure attempts to address these concerns, but influence operates through channels that extend far beyond formal voting rights.

Most importantly, the precedent signals to other nations that America no longer trusts market mechanisms for strategic competition. This may accelerate similar interventions globally, creating a world where technological development increasingly reflects state priorities rather than commercial efficiency. Such evolution could enhance strategic autonomy whilst reducing the innovation that emerges from competitive pressure.

The Intel intervention thus marks America's entry into explicit technological statecraft. Whether this enhances or undermines long-term competitiveness depends entirely on execution—a challenge that neither pure markets nor state ownership automatically solves.

Success requires acknowledging that America now competes in a world where other nations treat technology as an extension of state power. The question is not whether such interventions will continue, but whether America can design them more effectively than its competitors. The Intel experiment provides the first test of that capability.

As technological competition intensifies, America's abandonment of ideological purity for strategic pragmatism may prove either prescient or costly. Either way, the old rules no longer apply.

#politics